Menu Expand

Cite JOURNAL ARTICLE

Style

Barro, R., Gordon, D. A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model. Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, 52(4), 505-526. https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.52.4.505
Barro, Robert J. and Gordon, David B. "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model" Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital 52.4, 2019, 505-526. https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.52.4.505
Barro, Robert J./Gordon, David B. (2019): A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model, in: Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, vol. 52, iss. 4, 505-526, [online] https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.52.4.505

Format

A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model

Barro, Robert J. | Gordon, David B.

Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, Vol. 52 (2019), Iss. 4 : pp. 505–526

Additional Information

Article Details

Author Details

Prof. Dr. Robert Barro, Harvard University, Department of Economics, Littauer Center M 218, 1805 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA.

Prof. Dr. David B. Gordon, Clemson University, Department of Economics, 105 Sikes Hall, Clemson, SC 29634, USA

References

  1. Barro, R. J. (1976): Rational Expectations and the Role of Monetary Policy, J. Monetary Econ. 2, January 1976: 1–32.  Google Scholar
  2. Barro, R. J. (1977): Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States, A.E.R. 67, March 1977: 101–15.  Google Scholar
  3. Barro, R. J. (1981): Unanticipated Money Growth and Economic Activity in the United States, in Money, Expectations, and Business Cycles: Essays in Macroeconomics, New York: Academic Press, 1981.  Google Scholar
  4. Barro, R. J. (1983): Inflationary Finance under Discretion and Rules, Canadian J. Econ., Vol. 16. February 1983, pp. 1–16.  Google Scholar
  5. Barro, R. J./Gordon, D. B. (1981): A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural-Rate Model, Working Paper no. 807, Cambridge, Mass.: Nat. Bur. Econ. Res., November 1981.  Google Scholar
  6. Barro, R. J./Gordon, D. B. (1983): Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy, J. Monetary Econ. 12, July 1983: in press.  Google Scholar
  7. Buchanan, J. M. (1962): The Criterion of Monetary Constitutions, in In Search of a Monetary Constitution, edited by Leland B. Yeager, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press, 1962.  Google Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J. M./Tullock, G. (1962): The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor: Univ. Michigan Press, 1962.  Google Scholar
  9. Calvo, G. A. (1978): On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in a Monetary Economy, Econometrica 46, November 1978, pp. 1411–1428 (a).  Google Scholar
  10. Calvo, G. A. (1978): Optimal Seigniorage from Money Creation: An Analysis in Terms of the Optimum Balance of Payments Deficit Problem, J. Monetary Econ. 4, August 1978, pp. 503–517 (b).  Google Scholar
  11. Friedman, B. M. (1979): Optimal Expectation and the Extreme Information Assumptions of ‘Rational Expectations’ Macromodels, J. Monetary Econ. 5, January 1979, pp. 23–41.  Google Scholar
  12. Friedman, J. W. (1971): A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames, Rev. Econ. Studies 38, January 1971, pp. 1–12.  Google Scholar
  13. Gordon, D. B. (1980): Dynamic Equilibria with Purposive Policymaking, unpublished manuscript, Chicago: Univ. Chicago, Dept. Econ., November 1980.  Google Scholar
  14. Hercowitz, Z. (1981): Money and the Dispersion of Relative Prices, J.P.E. 89, April 1981, pp. 328–356.  Google Scholar
  15. Kreps, D. M./Wilson, R. B. (1980): On the Chain-Store Paradox and Predation: Reputation for Toughness, unpublished manuscript, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Univ., July 1980.  Google Scholar
  16. Kydland, F. E./Prescott, E. C. (1977): Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans, J.P.E. 85, June 1977, pp. 473–491.  Google Scholar
  17. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1972): Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, J. Econ. Theory 4, April 1972, pp. 103–124.  Google Scholar
  18. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1973): Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs, A.E.R. 63, June 1973, pp. 326–334.  Google Scholar
  19. Radner, R. (1979): Collusive Behavior in Noncooperative Epsilon-Equilibria of Oligopolies with Long but Finite Lines, unpublished manuscript, Murray Hill, N.J.: Bell Laboratories, August 1979.  Google Scholar
  20. Sargent, T. J./Wallace, N. (1975): ‘Rational’ Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule, J.P.E. 83, April 1975, pp. 241–254.  Google Scholar
  21. Taylor, J. B. (1975): Monetary Policy during a Transition to Rational Expectations. J.P.E. 83, October 1975, pp. 1009–1022.  Google Scholar
  22. Barro, R. J. (1976): Rational Expectations and the Role of Monetary Policy, J. Monetary Econ. 2, January 1976: 1–32.  Google Scholar
  23. Barro, R. J. (1977): Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States, A.E.R. 67, March 1977: 101–15.  Google Scholar
  24. Barro, R. J. (1981): Unanticipated Money Growth and Economic Activity in the United States, in Money, Expectations, and Business Cycles: Essays in Macroeconomics, New York: Academic Press, 1981.  Google Scholar
  25. Barro, R. J. (1983): Inflationary Finance under Discretion and Rules, Canadian J. Econ., Vol. 16. February 1983, pp. 1–16.  Google Scholar
  26. Barro, R. J./Gordon, D. B. (1981): A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural-Rate Model, Working Paper no. 807, Cambridge, Mass.: Nat. Bur. Econ. Res., November 1981.  Google Scholar
  27. Barro, R. J./Gordon, D. B. (1983): Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy, J. Monetary Econ. 12, July 1983: in press.  Google Scholar
  28. Buchanan, J. M. (1962): The Criterion of Monetary Constitutions, in In Search of a Monetary Constitution, edited by Leland B. Yeager, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press, 1962.  Google Scholar
  29. Buchanan, J. M./Tullock, G. (1962): The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor: Univ. Michigan Press, 1962.  Google Scholar
  30. Calvo, G. A. (1978): On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in a Monetary Economy, Econometrica 46, November 1978, pp. 1411–1428 (a).  Google Scholar
  31. Calvo, G. A. (1978): Optimal Seigniorage from Money Creation: An Analysis in Terms of the Optimum Balance of Payments Deficit Problem, J. Monetary Econ. 4, August 1978, pp. 503–517 (b).  Google Scholar
  32. Friedman, B. M. (1979): Optimal Expectation and the Extreme Information Assumptions of ‘Rational Expectations’ Macromodels, J. Monetary Econ. 5, January 1979, pp. 23–41.  Google Scholar
  33. Friedman, J. W. (1971): A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames, Rev. Econ. Studies 38, January 1971, pp. 1–12.  Google Scholar
  34. Gordon, D. B. (1980): Dynamic Equilibria with Purposive Policymaking, unpublished manuscript, Chicago: Univ. Chicago, Dept. Econ., November 1980.  Google Scholar
  35. Hercowitz, Z. (1981): Money and the Dispersion of Relative Prices, J.P.E. 89, April 1981, pp. 328–356.  Google Scholar
  36. Kreps, D. M./Wilson, R. B. (1980): On the Chain-Store Paradox and Predation: Reputation for Toughness, unpublished manuscript, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Univ., July 1980.  Google Scholar
  37. Kydland, F. E./Prescott, E. C. (1977): Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans, J.P.E. 85, June 1977, pp. 473–491.  Google Scholar
  38. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1972): Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, J. Econ. Theory 4, April 1972, pp. 103–124.  Google Scholar
  39. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1973): Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs, A.E.R. 63, June 1973, pp. 326–334.  Google Scholar
  40. Radner, R. (1979): Collusive Behavior in Noncooperative Epsilon-Equilibria of Oligopolies with Long but Finite Lines, unpublished manuscript, Murray Hill, N.J.: Bell Laboratories, August 1979.  Google Scholar
  41. Sargent, T. J./Wallace, N. (1975): ‘Rational’ Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule, J.P.E. 83, April 1975, pp. 241–254.  Google Scholar
  42. Taylor, J. B. (1975): Monetary Policy during a Transition to Rational Expectations. J.P.E. 83, October 1975, pp. 1009–1022.  Google Scholar

Abstract

A discretionary policymaker can create surprise inflation, which may reduce unemployment and raise government revenue. But when people understand the policymaker’s objectives, these surprises can- not occur systematically. In equilibrium people form expectations rationally and the policymaker optimizes in each period, subject to the way that people form expectations. Then, we find that (1) the rates of monetary growth and inflation are excessive; (2) these rates depend on the slope of the Phillips curve, the natural unemployment rate, and other variables that affect the benefits and costs from inflation; (3) the monetary authority behaves countercyclically; and (4) unemployment is independent of monetary policy. Outcomes improve if rules commit future policy choices in the appropriate manner. The value of these commitments-which amount to long- term contracts between the government and the private sector- underlies the argument for rules over discretion.

The primary purpose of this paper is to develop a positive theory of monetary policy and inflation. On the one hand, the theory turns out to accord with two perceptions about the world in recent years:

1. Average rates of inflation and monetary growth are excessive relative to an efficiency criterion.

2. There is a tendency to pursue activist, countercyclical monetary policies

Yet the model exhibits three other properties:

3. The unemployment rate – our proxy for real economic activity – is invariant with monetary policy (neglecting the familiar deadweight-loss aspect of inflation).

4. The policymaker and the public all act rationally, subject to their environments.

5. The policymaker’s objectives reflect the public’s preferences.

Natural rate models with rational expectations – such as Sargent and Wallace (1975) – suggest that the systematic parts of monetary policy are irrelevant for real economic activity. Some empirical evidence on the real effects of monetary disturbances in the post-World War II United States (e.?g., Barro 1977, 1981) is consistent with this result – in particular, there is some support for the proposition that anticipated monetary changes are neutral with respect to output, unemployment, and so on. On the other hand, these empirical studies and others indicated the presence of countercyclical monetary policy at least for the post-World War II United States – rises in the unemployment rate appear to generate subsequent expansions in monetary growth. Within the natural rate framework, it is difficult to reconcile this countercyclical monetary behavior with rationality of the policy-maker. A principal object of our analysis is to achieve this reconciliation. The natural rate models that have appeared in the macroeconomics literature of the last de­cade share the characteristic that policy choice is over a class of prespecified monetary rules. With the policy rule predetermined, there is no scope for ongoing policymaking; discretionary policy choice is excluded a priori. If private agents can deduce the characteristics of the monetary process once it is implemented, it defines their expectations. Thus, the policy decision is made subject to the constraint that agents’ expectations of future monetary policy will equal the realization. This framework allows the analysis to be reduced to a pair of single-agent decision problems, which can be considered independently. But, this approach cannot deal with the game-theoretic situation that arises when policy decisions are made on an ongoing basis. In our framework an equilibrium will include the following features:

a) a decision rule for private agents, which determines their actions as a function of their current information,

b) an expectations function, which determines the expectations of private agents as a function of their current information, and

c) a policy rule, which specifies the behavior of policy instruments as a function of the policymaker’s current information set.

The outcome is said to be a rational expectations equilibrium if, first, the decision rule specified in a is optimal for agents given their expectations as calculated under b; and second, it is optimal for the policymaker, whose actions are described by c, to perform in accordance with agents’ expectations b, given that the policymaker recognizes the form of the private decision rules under a. Faced by a maximizing policymaker, it would be unreasonable for agents to maintain expectations from which they know it will be in the policymaker’s interest to deviate.

If policy is precommitted, the only reasonable expectations that agents can hold are those defined by the rule. But, if policy is sequentially chosen, the equality of policy expectations and realizations is a characteristic of equilibrium – not a prior constraint. We have to determine which expectations agents can reasonably expect to be realized.

We view the policymaker as attempting to maximize an objective that reflects “society’s” preferences on inflation and unemployment. (Additional arguments for the preference function are mentioned later.) Although the equilibrium involves a path of unemployment that is invariant with policy, the rational policymaker adopts an activist rule. The extent of countercyclical response depends, among other things, on society’s relative dislikes for inflation and unemployment. There is an apparent contradiction because the policymaker pursues an activist policy that ends up having no desirable effects – in fact, unemployment is unaltered but inflation ends up being excessive. This outcome reflects the assumed inability of the policymaker – that is, of the institutional apparatus that is set up to manage monetary affairs – to commit its course of future actions. This feature has been stressed in an important paper by Kydland and Prescott (1977). If commitment were feasible through legal arrangements or other procedures, the countercyclical aspect of monetary policy would disappear (and, abstracting from costs of erecting and maintaining institutions, everyone would be better off). When this type of advance restriction is precluded, so that the policymaker sets instruments at each date subject only to the initial conditions prevailing for that date (which do not include restraints on policy choices), the equilibrium may involve an activist form of policy. This solution conforms to optimal behavior of private agents subject to a rationally anticipated policy rule. It corresponds also to optimality for the policymaker each period, subject to agents’ decision rules. Although an equilibrium obtains, the results are suboptimal, relative to outcomes where commitment is permitted. Given an environment where this type of policy commitment is absent – as appears to characterize the United States and other countries in recent years – the results constitute a positive theory of monetary growth and inflation.

We illustrate the results with a simple model, which comes from an example in Kydland and Prescott (1977, pp. 477–80). We augment their example along the lines detailed in Gordon (1980) to include a theory of expectations formation. People form their expectations by effectively solving the problem that the optimizing policymaker will face. The policymaker’s problem is then conditioned on the expectations function of private agents. Ultimately, there are no systematic differences between expected and realized inflation. But this property emerges as part of the equilibrium rather than as a constraint on the policy problem.