Menu Expand

Cite JOURNAL ARTICLE

Style

Oakes, I. Max Weber and Ordoliberalism: How Weber’s Kulturkritik Contributed to the Foundation of Ordoliberal Socio-Economic Thought. Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch, 140(2), 177-204. https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.140.2.177
Oakes, Isabel "Max Weber and Ordoliberalism: How Weber’s Kulturkritik Contributed to the Foundation of Ordoliberal Socio-Economic Thought" Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch 140.2, 2020, 177-204. https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.140.2.177
Oakes, Isabel (2020): Max Weber and Ordoliberalism: How Weber’s Kulturkritik Contributed to the Foundation of Ordoliberal Socio-Economic Thought, in: Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch, vol. 140, iss. 2, 177-204, [online] https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.140.2.177

Format

Max Weber and Ordoliberalism: How Weber’s Kulturkritik Contributed to the Foundation of Ordoliberal Socio-Economic Thought

Oakes, Isabel

Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch, Vol. 140 (2020), Iss. 2 : pp. 177–204

2 Citations (CrossRef)

Additional Information

Article Details

Author Details

Isabel Oakes, Faculty of History, University of Oxford, 41 – 47 George St, Oxford OX1 2BE, United Kingdom.

Cited By

  1. Utilitarian and Ideological Determinants of Attitudes towards Immigration: Germany Before and After the “Migration Crisis”

    Welsch, Heinz

    Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch, Vol. 141 (2021), Iss. 3 P.215

    https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.141.3.215 [Citations: 0]
  2. Coining Neoliberalism: Interwar Germany and the Neglected Origins of a Pejorative Moniker

    Magness, Phillip W.

    Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch, Vol. 141 (2021), Iss. 3 P.189

    https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.141.3.189 [Citations: 1]

References

  1. Angner, E. 2004. “Did Hayek Commit the Naturalistic Fallacy?” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26 (3): 349 – 61.  Google Scholar
  2. Audier, S. 2019. “A Grand Misunderstanding: Foucault and German Neoliberalism, Then and Now.” In Foucault, Neoliberalism, and Beyond, edited by S. W. Sawyer and D. Steinmetz-Jenkins, 33 – 52. London: Rowman & Littlefield.  Google Scholar
  3. Biebricher, T. 2011. “The Biopolitics of Ordoliberalism.” Foucault Studies 12: 171 – 91.  Google Scholar
  4. Biebricher, T and F. Vogelmann, eds. 2017. The Birth of Austerity: German Ordoliberalism and Contemporary Neoliberalism. London: Rowman & Littlefield.  Google Scholar
  5. Bilger, F. 1964. La pensée économique libérale dans l’Allemagne contemporaine. Paris: R. Pichon et R. Durand-Auzias.  Google Scholar
  6. Boettke, P. J. and V. H. Storr. 2002. “Post-Classical Political Economy: Polity, Society and Economy in Weber, Mises and Hayek.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 61 (1): 161 – 91.  Google Scholar
  7. Böhm, F., W. Eucken, and H. Grossmann-Doerth. 1989. “The Ordo Manifesto of 1936.” In Germany’s Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, edited by A. Peacock and H. Willgerodt, 15 – 26. New York: St. Martin’s Press.  Google Scholar
  8. Bonefeld, W. 2012. “Freedom and the Strong State: On German Ordoliberalism.” New Political Economy 17 (5): 633 – 56.  Google Scholar
  9. Bonefeld, W. 2013. “Human Economy and Social policy: On Ordo-liberalism and Political Authority.” History of the Human Sciences 26 (2): 106 – 25.  Google Scholar
  10. Bonefeld, W. 2014. Critical Theory and the Critique of Political Economy: On Subversion and Negative Reason. London: Bloomsbury.  Google Scholar
  11. Brunnermeier, M. K., H. James and J.-P. Landau. 2016. The Euro and the Battle of Ideas. Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Google Scholar
  12. Burgin, A. 2012. The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets since the Depression. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  Google Scholar
  13. Caldwell, B. and J. Reiss. 2006. “Notes and Commentary: Hayek, Logic, and the Naturalistic Fallacy.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28 (3): 359 – 70.  Google Scholar
  14. Callahan, G. 2007. “Reconciling Weber and Mises on Understanding Human Action.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 66 (5): 889 – 99.  Google Scholar
  15. Christ, K. 2018. “A Measure of Judgments – Wilhelm Röpke’s Methodological Heresy.” ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 69: 35 – 50.  Google Scholar
  16. Clarke, S. 1991. Marx, Marginalism and Modern Sociology. London: Palgrave Macmillan.  Google Scholar
  17. Commun, P. and S. Kolev, eds. 2018. Wilhelm Röpke (1899 – 1966): A Liberal Political Economist and Conservative Social Philosopher. Cham: Springer.  Google Scholar
  18. Dold, M. and T. Krieger, eds. 2020. Ordoliberalism and European Economic Policy: Between Realpolitik and Economic Utopia. London: Routledge.  Google Scholar
  19. Dörr, J., N. Goldschmidt, G. Kubon-Gilke, and W. Sesselmeier, eds. 2016. Vitalpolitik, Inklusion und der sozialstaatliche Diskurs: Theoretische Reflexionen und sozialpolitische Implikationen. Münster: LIT Verlag.  Google Scholar
  20. Eucken, W. 1952. Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).  Google Scholar
  21. Foucault, M. 2008. The Birth of Biopolitics: Lectures at the Collège de France 1978 – 1979. Translated by G. Burchell. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.  Google Scholar
  22. Gane, N. 2012. Max Weber and Contemporary Capitalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.  Google Scholar
  23. Gane, N. 2014. “Sociology and Neoliberalism: A Missing History.” Sociology 48 (5): 1092 – 106.  Google Scholar
  24. Gerber, D. J. 1994. “Constitutionalizing the Economy: German Neoliberalism, Competition Law and the ‘New’ Europe.” American Journal of Comparative Law 42 (1): 25 – 84.  Google Scholar
  25. Ghosh, P. 2014. Max Weber and The Protestant Ethic: Twin Histories. Oxford: Oxford University Press.  Google Scholar
  26. Ghosh, P. 2016. Max Weber in Context: Essays in the History of German Ideas c. 1870 – 1930. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz Verlag.  Google Scholar
  27. Glasman, M. 1996. Unnecessary Suffering: Managing Market Utopia. London: Verso.  Google Scholar
  28. Goldschmidt, N. (ed.). 2005. Wirtschaft, Politik und Freiheit: Freiburger Wirtschaftswissenschaftler und der Widerstand. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.  Google Scholar
  29. Goldschmidt, N. 2013. “Walter Eucken’s Place in the History of Ideas.” Review of Austrian Economics 26 (2): 127 – 47.  Google Scholar
  30. Goldschmidt, N. and H. G. Nutzinger. 2009. “Handlung und Verhalten in der Ökonomie: Eine Einführung aus kulturökonomischer Sicht.” In Vom homo oeconomicus zum homo culturalis: Handlung und Verhalten in der Ökonomie, edited by N. Goldschmidt and H. G. Nutzinger, 9 – 22. Münster: LIT Verlag  Google Scholar
  31. Goldschmidt, N. and H. Rauchenschwandtner. 2018. “The Philosophy of Social Market Economy: Michel Foucault’s Analysis of Ordoliberalism.” Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch 138 (2): 157 – 84.  Google Scholar
  32. Goldschmidt, N. and M. Wohlgemuth, eds. 2008. Grundtexte zur Freiburger Tradition der Ordnungsökonomik. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.  Google Scholar
  33. Haselbach, D. 1991. Autoritärer Liberalismus und Soziale Marktwirtschaft: Gesellschaft und Politik im Ordoliberalismus. Baden-Baden: Nomos.  Google Scholar
  34. Hayek, F. A. (ed.). (1935) 1963. Collectivist Economic Planning. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.  Google Scholar
  35. Hekman, S. J. 1983. “Weber’s Ideal Type: A Contemporary Reassessment.” Polity 16 (1): 119 – 37.  Google Scholar
  36. Hennis, W. 1991. “The Pitiless ‘Sobriety of Judgement’: Max Weber between Carl Menger and Gustav von Schmoller – The Academic Politics of Value Freedom.” History of the Human Sciences 4 (1): 27 – 59.  Google Scholar
  37. Hien, J. and C. Joerges, eds. 2017. Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule of Economics. Oxford: Hart Publishing.  Google Scholar
  38. Holton, R. J. and B. S. Turner. 2010. Max Weber on Economy and Society. London: Routledge.  Google Scholar
  39. Jackson, B. 2010. “At the Origins of Neo-liberalism: The Free Economy and the Strong State, 1930 – 1947.” The Historical Journal 53 (1): 129 – 51.  Google Scholar
  40. Kaesler, D. 1981. “Der Streit um die Bestimmung der Soziologie auf den Deutschen Soziologentagen 1910 – 1930.” Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie Sonderheft 23: 199 – 244.  Google Scholar
  41. Kahan, A. S. 2012. “Max Weber and Warren Buffett: Looking for the Lost Charisma of Capitalism.” Society 49 (1): 144 – 50.  Google Scholar
  42. Kolev, S. 2017. Neoliberale Staatsverständnisse im Vergleich. Berlin: De Gruyter.  Google Scholar
  43. Kolev, S. 2018a. “The Abandoned Übervater: Max Weber and the Neoliberals.” Working Papers of the Center for the History of Political Economy 2018 – 21, Duke University.  Google Scholar
  44. Kolev, S. 2018b. “Early Economic Sociology and Contextual Economics: The Weber-Wieser Connection.” Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch 138 (1): 1 – 30.  Google Scholar
  45. Kolev, S. 2019. “Antipathy for Heidelberg, Sympathy for Freiburg? Vincent Ostrom on Max Weber, Walter Eucken, and the Compound History of Order.” Discussion Paper 19/06, Freiburg Discussion Papers on Constitutional Economics, Walter Eucken Institut.  Google Scholar
  46. Kolev, S. 2020. “The Legacy of Max Weber and the Early Austrians.” Review of Austrian Economics 33 (1/2): 33 – 54.  Google Scholar
  47. Kolev, S. and N. Goldschmidt. 2020. “Kulturpessimismus als Provokation: Wilhelm Röpkes Ringen mit der Moderne.” ZfP Zeitschrift für Politik 67 (2): 214 – 34.  Google Scholar
  48. Kolev, S., N. Goldschmidt, and J.-O. Hesse. 2020. “Debating Liberalism: Walter Eucken, F. A. Hayek and the Early History of the Mont Pèlerin Society.” Review of Austrian Economics 33 (4): 433 – 63.  Google Scholar
  49. Lavoie, D. 2015. Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered. Arlington: Mercatus Center at George Mason University.  Google Scholar
  50. Maclachlan, F. 2017. “Max Weber within the Methodenstreit.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 41 (4): 1161 – 75.  Google Scholar
  51. Magness, P. W. 2020. “Coining Neoliberalism: Interwar Germany and the Neglected Origins of a Pejorative Moniker.” Accessed June 7, 2021. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3681101.  Google Scholar
  52. Marcuse, H. (1965) 2009. “Industrialization and Capitalism in the Work of Max Weber.” In Negations: Essays in Critical Theory, translated by J. J. Shapiro, 151 – 70. London: MayFly Books.  Google Scholar
  53. Mardellat, P. 2009. “Max Weber’s Critical Response to Theoretical Economics.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16 (4): 599 – 624.  Google Scholar
  54. McAdam, M., S. Kolev, and E. Dekker. 2018. “Methods for Understanding Economic Change: Socio-Economics and German Political Economy, 1896 – 1938.” Journal of Contextual Economics – Schmollers Jahrbuch 138 (3/4): 185 – 97.  Google Scholar
  55. McNay, L. 2009. “Self as Enterprise: Dilemmas of Control and Resistance in Foucault’s The Birth of Biopolitics.” Theory, Culture & Society 26 (6): 55 – 77.  Google Scholar
  56. Meier-Rust, K. 1993. Alexander Rüstow: Geschichtsdeutung und liberales Engagement. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.  Google Scholar
  57. Mirowski, P. and D. Plehwe, eds. 2009. The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  Google Scholar
  58. Mises, L. v. (1920) 2012. Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth. Translated by S. Adler. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.  Google Scholar
  59. Mises, L. v. (1922) 1962. Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Translated by J. Kahane. New Haven: Yale University Press.  Google Scholar
  60. Moetteli, C. 1953. “A Portrait of Wilhelm Röpke and the Regeneration of Liberalism.” World Liberalism: The Journal of the Liberal International 3 (3): 12 – 24.  Google Scholar
  61. Mommsen, W. (1959) 1984. Max Weber and German Politics 1890 – 1920. Translated by M. S. Steinberg. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.  Google Scholar
  62. Mommsen, W. 2000. “Max Weber’s ‘Grand Sociology’: The Origins and Composition of ‘Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft: Soziologie.’” History and Theory 39 (3): 364 – 83.  Google Scholar
  63. Mueller, G. H. 1982. “Socialism and Capitalism in the Work of Max Weber.” The British Journal of Sociology 33 (2): 151 – 71.  Google Scholar
  64. O’Neill, J. 1996. “Who Won the Socialist Calculation Debate?” History of Political Thought 17 (3): 431 – 42.  Google Scholar
  65. Oppenheimer, F. 1995. Theoretische Grundlegung: Gesammelte Schriften, Vol. 1, edited by E.–V. Kotowski. Berlin: Akademie Verlag.  Google Scholar
  66. Parsons, S. D. 2003. Money, Time and Rationality in Max Weber: Austrian Connections. London: Routledge.  Google Scholar
  67. Rath, C. 1998. Staat, Gesellschaft und Wirtschaft bei Max Weber und bei Walter Eucken: Eine theorievergleichende Studie. Egelsbach: Ha¨nsel-Hohenhausen.  Google Scholar
  68. Reinhoudt, J. and S. Audier. 2018. The Walter Lippmann Colloquium: The Birth of Neo-Liberalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.  Google Scholar
  69. Rieter, H. and M. Schmolz. 1993. “The Ideas of German Ordoliberalism 1938 – 45: Pointing the Way to a New Economic Order.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 1 (1): 87 – 114.  Google Scholar
  70. Röpke, W. (1937) 1963. Economics of the Free Society. Translated by P. M. Boarman. Chicago: Henry Regnery.  Google Scholar
  71. Röpke, W. 1942. International Economic Disintegration. London: William Hodge.  Google Scholar
  72. Röpke, W. (1942) 1950. The Social Crisis of Our Time. Translated by A. and P. Schiffer Jacobsohn. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.  Google Scholar
  73. Röpke, W. 1946. The German Question. Translated by E. W. Dickes. London: George Allen & Unwin.  Google Scholar
  74. Röpke, W. 1948. Civitas Humana: A Humane Order of Society. Translated by C. S. Fox. London: William Hodge.  Google Scholar
  75. Röpke, W. (1948) 2002. The Moral Foundation of Civil Society. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.  Google Scholar
  76. Röpke, W. (1951) 1987. “Welfare, Freedom and Inflation.” In 2 Essays by Wilhelm Roepke: The Problem of Economic Order / Welfare, Freedom and Inflation, edited by J. Overbeek, 49 – 103. Lanham: University Press of America.  Google Scholar
  77. Röpke, W. 1969. Against the Tide. Translated by E. Henderson. Chicago: Henry Regnery.  Google Scholar
  78. Rüstow, A. 1942. “Appendix: General Sociological Causes of the Economic Disintegration and Possibilities of Reconstruction.” In International Economic Disintegration, by W. Röpke, 267 – 83. London: William Hodge.  Google Scholar
  79. Rüstow, A. 1943. “Der moderne Pflicht- und Arbeitsmensch: Herkunft und Zukunft.” Revue de la Faculté des sciences économiques de l’Université d’Istanbul 3 (3/4): 107 – 36.  Google Scholar
  80. Rüstow, A. 1950. Ortsbestimmung der Gegenwart: Eine universalgeschichtliche Kulturkritik. Band 1: Ursprung der Herrschaft. Erlenbach-Zurich: Eugen Rentsch.  Google Scholar
  81. Rüstow, A. (1950) 1980. Freedom and Domination. Edited by D. A. Rüstow, translated by S. Attanasio. Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Google Scholar
  82. Rüstow, A. 1963. Rede und Antwort: 21 Reden und viele Diskussionsbeiträge aus den Jahren 1932 bis 1962, edited by W. Hoch. Ludwigsburg: Martin Hoch.  Google Scholar
  83. Rüstow, A. 2009. Die Religion der Marktwirtschaft. Münster: LIT Verlag.  Google Scholar
  84. Scott, A. 2000. “Capitalism, Weber and Democracy.” Max Weber Studies 1 (1): 35 – 55.  Google Scholar
  85. Siems, M. and G. Schnyder. 2013. “Ordoliberal Lessons for Economic Stability: Different Kinds of Regulation, Not More Regulation.” Governance 27 (3): 377 – 96.  Google Scholar
  86. Slobodian, Q. 2018. Globalists: The End of Empire and the Birth of Neoliberalism. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  Google Scholar
  87. Slobodian, Q. 2019. “Perfect Capitalism, Imperfect Humans: Race, Migration and the Limits of Ludwig von Mises’s Globalism.” Contemporary European History 28 (2): 143 – 55.  Google Scholar
  88. Swedberg, R. 1998a. “Max Weber’s Manifesto in Economic Sociology.” European Journal of Sociology 39 (2): 379 – 98.  Google Scholar
  89. Swedberg, R. 1998b. Max Weber and the Idea of Economic Sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Google Scholar
  90. Swedberg, R. 2017. “How to Use Max Weber’s Ideal Type in Sociological Analysis.” Journal of Classical Sociology 18 (3): 181 – 96.  Google Scholar
  91. Tribe, K. 1995. Strategies of Economic Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.  Google Scholar
  92. Tribe, K. 2010. “Max Weber and the ‘New Economics.’” In Austrian Economics in Transition: From Carl Menger to Friedrich Hayek, edited by H. Hagemann, T. Nishizawa, and Y. Ikeda, 62 – 88. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.  Google Scholar
  93. Vanberg, V. J. 1998. “Freiburg School of Law and Economics.” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 2, edited by P. Newman, 172 – 9. London: Palgrave.  Google Scholar
  94. Vanberg, V. J. 2004. The Freiburg School: Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism. Discussion Paper 04/11, Freiburg Discussion Papers on Constitutional Economics, Walter Eucken Institut.  Google Scholar
  95. Vanberg, V. J. 2013. “Ordnungspolitik, the Freiburg School and the Reason of Rules.” Analele Universitatii din Bucuresti. Seria Stiinte Politice 1: 23 – 36.  Google Scholar
  96. Vatiero, M. 2014. “Dominant Market Position and Ordoliberalism.” International Review of Economics 62: 291 – 306.  Google Scholar
  97. Weber, M. (1898) 1990. Grundriß zu den Vorlesungen über Allgemeine (“theoretische”) Nationalökonomie (1898). Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).  Google Scholar
  98. Weber, M. (1903) 2012. “Roscher’s ‘Historical Method.’” In Max Weber: Collected Methodological Writings, edited by H. H. Bruun and S. Whimster, 3 – 28. London: Routledge.  Google Scholar
  99. Weber, M. (1904/1905) 1992. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Translated by T. Parsons. London: Routledge.  Google Scholar
  100. Weber, M. (1917) 1994. “Suffrage and Democracy in Germany.” In Weber: Political Writings, edited by P. Lassman and R. Speirs, 80 – 129. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.  Google Scholar
  101. Weber, M. 1918. Parlament und Regierung im neugeordneten Deutschland: Zur politischen Kritik des Beamtentums und Parteiwesens. Munich: Duncker & Humblot.  Google Scholar
  102. Weber, M. (1918) 1967. Socialism. Translated by H. F. Dickie-Clark. Occasional Paper Nr. 11 of the Institute for Social Research, University of Kwa-Zulu Natal.  Google Scholar
  103. Weber, M. (1918) 1994. “Parliament and Government in Germany under a New Political Order.” In Weber: Political Writings, edited by P. Lassman and R. Speirs, 130 – 271. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.  Google Scholar
  104. Weber, M. (1922) 1978. Economy and Society. Translated by G. Roth and C. Wittich. Berkeley: University of California Press.  Google Scholar
  105. Weber, M. (1922) 2019. Economy and Society. Translated by K. Tribe. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  Google Scholar
  106. Weber, M. 1949. The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Translated by E. A. Shils and H. A. Finch. Glencoe: The Free Press.  Google Scholar
  107. Whimster, S. 2019. “Economics and Society and the Fate of Liberal Capitalism.” In The Oxford Handbook of Max Weber, edited by E. Hanke, L. Scaff, and S. Whimster, 21 – 46. New York: Oxford University Press.  Google Scholar
  108. Wigger, A. 2017. “Debunking the Myth of the Ordoliberal Influence on Post-war European Integration.” In Ordoliberalism, Law and the Rule of Economics, edited by J. Hien and C. Joerges, 161 – 78. Oxford: Hart Publishing.  Google Scholar
  109. Wörsdörfer, M. and C. Dethlefs. 2016. “Homo oeconomicus oder Homo culturalis? – Aktuelle Herausforderungen für das ordoliberale Menschenbild.” ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 63: 135 – 57.  Google Scholar

Abstract

This study aims to uncover Max Weber as a direct and indirect influence on Alexander Rüstow and Wilhelm Röpke and the emergence of ordoliberal socio-economic thought in the 1930s and 40s. Weber contributed to the German Kulturkritik of the early 20th century that shaped the academic and socio-political climate in which the ordoliberals formed their own ideas. Weber also identified key societal issues to which the ordoliberals found concrete solutions, specifically their “Third Way” between laissez-faire capitalism and central planning as well as Vitalpolitik. This study finds that despite Weber’s relative neglect in epistemological studies of economics, his insights were incorporated into ordoliberal thought and beyond.