Menu Expand

Divisia-Geldmengenindizes

Cite JOURNAL ARTICLE

Style

Reischle, J. Divisia-Geldmengenindizes. . Ein Vorschlag zur theoretisch korrekten Erfassung des Geldes?. Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, 30(3), 445-486. https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.30.3.445
Reischle, Julian "Divisia-Geldmengenindizes. Ein Vorschlag zur theoretisch korrekten Erfassung des Geldes?. " Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital 30.3, 1997, 445-486. https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.30.3.445
Reischle, Julian (1997): Divisia-Geldmengenindizes, in: Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, vol. 30, iss. 3, 445-486, [online] https://doi.org/10.3790/ccm.30.3.445

Format

Divisia-Geldmengenindizes

Ein Vorschlag zur theoretisch korrekten Erfassung des Geldes?

Reischle, Julian

Credit and Capital Markets – Kredit und Kapital, Vol. 30 (1997), Iss. 3 : pp. 445–486

Additional Information

Article Details

Author Details

Julian Reischle, Würzburg

References

  1. Barnett, William A. (1978): The User Cost of Money, in: Economics Letters, Vol. 1, S. 145 - 149.  Google Scholar
  2. Barnett, William A. (1980): Economic Monetary Aggregates, in: Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 14, S. 11-48.  Google Scholar
  3. Barnett, William A. (1981): Consumer Demand and Labour Market - Goods, Monetary Assets, and Time, North-Holland, New York.  Google Scholar
  4. Barnett, William A. (1982a): The Optimal Level of Monetary Aggregation, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 14, S. 687 - 710.  Google Scholar
  5. Barnett, William A. (1982b): Divisia Indices, in: Johnson, Norman und Samuel Kotz (Hrsg.), Encyclopedia of Statistical Sciences, Vol. 2, New York, S. 412 - 415.  Google Scholar
  6. Barnett, William A. (1987): The Microeconomic Theory of Monetary Aggregation, in: Barnett, William A. und Kenneth J. Singleton (Hrsg.), New Approaches to Monetary Economics, Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass., S. 115-168.  Google Scholar
  7. Barnett, William A. (1991): A Reply to Julio J. Rotemberg, in: Belongia, Micheal T. (Hrsg.), Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal Reserve System, Kluwer, Boston, S. 232 - 243.  Google Scholar
  8. Barnett, William A., Douglas Fisher und Apostolos Serletis (1992): Consumer Theory and the Demand for Money, in: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 30, S. 2086 - 2119.  Google Scholar
  9. Barnett, William A., Melvin Hinich und Piyu Yue (1991): Monitoring Monetary Aggregates Under Risk Aversion, in: Belongia, Micheal T. (Hrsg.), Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal Reserve System, Kluwer, Boston, S. 189 - 217.  Google Scholar
  10. Barnett, William A., Milka Kirova, Yi Liu, Meenakshi Paupathy, Ge Zhou und Piyu Yue (1994): Beyond the Risk Neutral Utility Function, Beitrag für die Konferenz „Divisia Monetary Aggregates - Right in Theory, Useful in Practice?“, 17./18. Oktober 1994, University of Mississippi, Oxford, Miss.  Google Scholar
  11. Belongia, Michael T. und James A. Chalfant (1989): The Changing Empirical Defintion of Money: Some Estimates from a Model of the Demand for Money Substitutes, in: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, S. 387 - 397.  Google Scholar
  12. Belongia, Michael T. und James A. Chalfant (1990): Alternative Measures of Money as Indicators of Inflation: A Survey and Some New Evidence, in: Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Vol. 72, S. 20 - 33.  Google Scholar
  13. Belongia, Michael T. und Alec K. Chrystal (1991): An Admissible Monetary Aggregate for the U.K., in: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 73, S. 491 - 502.  Google Scholar
  14. Bernanke, Ben S. und Alan S. Blinder (1988): Credit, Money, and Aggregate Demand, in: American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 78, S. 435 - 439.  Google Scholar
  15. Bofinger, Peter (1985): Währungswettbewerb, Carl Heymanns, Köln.  Google Scholar
  16. Bofinger, Peter, Julian Reischle und Andrea Schächter (1996): Geldpolitik -Ziele, Institutionen, Strategien, Instrumente, Vahlen, München.  Google Scholar
  17. Chetty, V. Karuppan (1969): On Measuring the Nearness of Near-Moneys, in: American Economic Review, Vol. 59, S. 270 - 281.  Google Scholar
  18. Clower, Robert A. (1967): A Reconsideration of the Microfoundations of Monetary Theory, in: Western Economic Journal, Vol. 6, S.1-8.  Google Scholar
  19. Deutsche Bundesbank (1988): Methodische Anmerkungen zur geldpolitischen Zielgröße „M3“, in: Monatsbericht der Deutschen Bundesbank, März 1988, S. 18 - 21.  Google Scholar
  20. Diewert, W. E. (1976): Exact and Superlative Index Numbers, in: Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 4, S. 115 - 145.  Google Scholar
  21. Diewert, W. E. (1978): Superlative Index Numbers and Consistency in Aggregation, in: Econometrica, Vol. 46, S. 883 - 900. - Diewert, W. E. (1980): Symmetry Conditions for Market Demand Functions, in: Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 47, S. 595 - 601.  Google Scholar
  22. Diewert, W. E. (1992): Index Numbers, in: Newman, Peter, Murray Milgate und John Eatwell (Hrsg.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money & Finance, Vol. 2, S. 364 - 379.  Google Scholar
  23. Diewert, W. E. (1993): Introduction, in: Diewert, W. E. und A. O. Nakamura (Hrsg.), Essays in Index Number Theory, Vol. 1, Kluwer, Dordrecht.  Google Scholar
  24. Divisia, François (1925): L’Indice Monétaire et la Théorie de la Monnaie, in: Revue d’Economie Politique, No. 39, S. 980-1008.  Google Scholar
  25. Donovan, Donal J. (1978): Modeling the Demand for Liquid Assets: An Application to Canada, in: IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 25, S. 676 - 704.  Google Scholar
  26. Drake, Leigh (1992): The Substitutabilitiy of Financial Assets in the U.K. and the Implications for Monetary Aggregation, in: The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 60, S. 221 - 248.  Google Scholar
  27. Eichhorn, Wolfgang und Joachim Voeller (1976): Theory of the Price Index, Springer, Berlin.  Google Scholar
  28. Ewis, Nabil A. und Douglas Fisher (1984): The Translog Utility Function and the Demand for Money in the United States, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 16, S. 34 - 52.  Google Scholar
  29. Ewis, Nabil A. und Douglas Fisher (1985): Toward a Consistent Estimate of the Demand for Monies: An Application of the Fourier Flexible Form, in: Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 7, S. 151 - 174.  Google Scholar
  30. Farr, Helen T. und Deborah Johnson (1985): Revisions in the Monetary Services (Divisia): Indexes of the Monetary Aggregates, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington.  Google Scholar
  31. Fayyad, Salam Khaled (1986): Monetary Asset Component Grouping and Aggregation: An Inquiry Into the Definition of Money, PhD Dissertation, The University of Texas at Austin.  Google Scholar
  32. Feenstra, Robert C. (1986): Functional Equivalence Between Liquidity Costs and the Utility of Money, in: Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 17, S. 271 - 291.  Google Scholar
  33. Fisher, Douglas (1989): Money Demand and Monetary Policy, Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York.  Google Scholar
  34. Fisher, Irving (1927): The Making of Index Numbers, 3. Auflage, wiederabgedruckt in: Reprints of Economic Classics, Augustus M. Kelley, New York, 1967.  Google Scholar
  35. Fisher, Paul, Suzanne Hudson und Mahmood Pradhan (1993): Divisia-Indices for Money: An Appraisal of Theory and Practice, Bank of England Working Paper Series No. 9.  Google Scholar
  36. Ford, J. L., W. S. Peng und A. W. Mullineux (1992): Financial Innovation and Divisia Monetary Aggregates, in: Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54, S. 87 - 102.  Google Scholar
  37. Friedman, Milton (1956): The Quantity Theory of Money - A Restatement, in: Friedman, Milton (Hrsg.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, Univ. of Chicago Press, Chicago.  Google Scholar
  38. Friedman, Milton und David Meiselman (1963): The Relative Stability of Monetary Velocity and the Investment Multiplier in the United States, 1897 - 1958, in: Brown, E. C. (Hrsg.), Stabilization Policies, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, S. 165 - 268.  Google Scholar
  39. Frisch, Ragnar (1930): Necessary and Sufficient Conditions Regarding the Form of an Index Number Which Shall Meet Certain of Fisher’s Tests, in: American Statistical Association Journal, Vol. 25, S. 397 - 406.  Google Scholar
  40. Gaab, Werner und Andy W. Mullineux (1996): Financial Innovation, Monetary Aggregates and Monetary Policy in the UK and Germany, in: Duwendag, Dieter (Hrsg.) Finanzmärkte, Finanzinnovationen und Geldpolitik, Schriften des Vereins für Socialpolitik, N.F. 242, S. 73-110.  Google Scholar
  41. Gerloff, W. (1947): Die Entstehung des Geldes und die Anfänge des Geldwesens, Frankfurt am Main.  Google Scholar
  42. Gertler, Mark (1988): Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 20, S. 559 - 588.  Google Scholar
  43. Green, John H. A. (1964): Aggregation in Economic Analysis, Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton.  Google Scholar
  44. Herrmann, Heinz, Hans-Eggert Reimers und Karl-Heinz Tödter (1994): Weighted Monetary Aggregates for Germany, Beitrag für die Konferenz „Divisia Monetary Aggregates - Right in Theory, Useful in Practice?“, 17./18. Oktober 1994, University of Mississippi, Oxford, Miss.  Google Scholar
  45. Hicks, John R. (1946): Value and Capital, 2. Auflage, Clarendon, Oxford.  Google Scholar
  46. Hicks, John R. (1967): Critical Essays in Monetary Theory, Oxford Univ. Press, Oxford.  Google Scholar
  47. Hulten, Charles R. (1987): Divisia Index, in: Newman, Peter, Murray Milgate und John Eatwell (Hrsg.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 1, S. 899 - 901.  Google Scholar
  48. Hutt, W. H. (1963): Keynesianism - Retrospect and Prospect, A Critical Restatement of Basic Economic Principles, Henry Regnery Comp., Chicago.  Google Scholar
  49. Issing, Otmar, Karl-Heinz Tödter, Heinz Herrmann und Hans-Eggert Reimers (1993): Zinsgewichtete Geldmengenaggregate und M3 - ein Vergleich, in: Kredit und Kapital, 26. Jahrgang, S. 1-21.  Google Scholar
  50. Kane, Edward J. (1964): Money as a Weighted Aggregate, in: Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, Vol. 24, S. 221-243.  Google Scholar
  51. Kayshap, AnilK. und Jeremy C. Stein (1994): Monetary Policy and Bank Lending, in: Mankiw, N. Gregory (Hrsg.), Monetary Policy, Univ. of Chicago Press, Chicago, S. 221 - 256.  Google Scholar
  52. Keynes, John Maynard (1930a): A Treatise on Money - The Pure Theory of Money, abgedruckt in: The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. V, Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1971.  Google Scholar
  53. Keynes, John Maynard (1930b): A Treatise on Money - The Applied Theory of Money, abgedruckt in: The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. VI, Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1971.  Google Scholar
  54. Krämer, Jörg Wilhelm (1996): Zinsgewichtete versus herkömmliche Geldmengenaggregate, Kieler Studien, Nr. 274, J. C. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck): Tübingen.  Google Scholar
  55. Leontief, Wassily (1947): Introduction to a Theory of the Internal Structure of Functional Relationships, in: Econometrica, Vol. 15, S. 361 - 373.  Google Scholar
  56. Mason, Will E. (1976): The Empirical Definition of Money: A Critique, in: Economic Inquiry, Vol. 14, S. 525 - 538.  Google Scholar
  57. Neubauer, Werner (1976): Uber Adäquationsprobleme in der Geldstatistik, in: Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv, Bd. 60, S. 357 - 389.  Google Scholar
  58. Pesek, Boris P. und Thomas R. Saving (1967): Money, Wealth, and Economic Theory, Macmillan, New York.  Google Scholar
  59. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1991): Commentary, in: Belongia, Michael T. (Hrsg.), Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal Reserve System, Kluwer, Boston, S. 223 - 231.  Google Scholar
  60. Samuelson, Paul A. (1947): Foundations of Economic Analysis, Harvard Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass.  Google Scholar
  61. Samuelson, Paul A. und S. Swamy (1974): Invariant Economic Index Numbers and Canonical Duality: Survey and Synthesis, in: American Economic Review, Vol. 64, S. 566 - 593.  Google Scholar
  62. Scharnagl, Michael (1996): Geldmengenaggregate unter Berücksichtigung struktureller Veränderungen an den Finanzmärkten, Diskussionspapier 2/96, Volkswirtschaftliche Forschungsgruppe der Deutschen Bundesbank.  Google Scholar
  63. Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1961): Konjunkturzyklen, Band 2, Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, Göttingen.  Google Scholar
  64. Serletis, Apostolos (1987 a): Monetary Asset Separability Tests, in: Barnett, William A. und Kenneth J. Singleton (Hrsg.), New Approaches to Monetary Economics, Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass., S. 169 - 182.  Google Scholar
  65. Serletis, Apostolos (1987 b): The Demand for Divisia M1, M2, and M3 in the United States, in: Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 9, S. 567 - 592.  Google Scholar
  66. Serletis, Apostolos (1991): The Demand for Divisia Money in the United States: A Dynamic Flexible Demand System, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 23, S. 35 - 52.  Google Scholar
  67. Serletis, Apostolos und A. Leslie Robb (1986): Divisia Aggregation and Substitutability Among Monetary Assets, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 18, S. 430 - 446.  Google Scholar
  68. Sono, M. (1961): The Effect of Price Changes on the Demand and Supply of Separable Goods, in: International Economic Review, Vol. 2, S. 239 - 271.  Google Scholar
  69. Spencer, Peter (1994): Portfolio Disequilibrium - Implications for the Divisia Approach to Monetary Aggregates, in: The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 62, S. 125 - 150.  Google Scholar
  70. Spencer, Peter (1995): Should the ECB Adopt a Divisia Monetary Aggregate? Beitrag für die Tagung von CEPR und Irving-Fischer-Gesellschaft mit dem Thema: What Monetary Policy for the European Central Bank? 9./10. Juni 1995, Königstein/Ts.  Google Scholar
  71. Swofford, James L. (1995): A Revealed Preference Analysis of Friedman and Schwartz Money, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 27, S. 154 - 164.  Google Scholar
  72. Swofford, James L. und Gerald A. Whitney (1986): Flexible Functional Forms and the Utility Approach to the Demand for Money: A Nonparametric Analysis, in: Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 18, S. 383 - 389.  Google Scholar
  73. Swofford, James L. und Gerald A. Whitney (1987): Nonparametric Tests of Utility Maximization and Weak Separability for Consumption, Leisure, and Money, in: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 69, S. 458 - 464.  Google Scholar
  74. Swofford, James L. und Gerald A. Whitney (1988): A Comparison of Nonparametric Tests of Weak Separabiltiy for Annual and Quarterly Data on Consumption, Leisure, and Money, in: Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 6, S. 241 - 246.  Google Scholar
  75. Swofford, James L. und Gerald A. Whitney (1992): The Canging Empirical Definiton of Money: A Comment, in: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, S. 1078-1081.  Google Scholar
  76. Swofford, James L. und Gerald A. Whitney (1994): A Revealed Preference Test for Weakly Separable Utility Maximization with Incomplete Adjustment, in: Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 60, S. 235 - 249.  Google Scholar
  77. Tödter, Karl-Heinz (1994): Eine Transaktionsorientierte Geldmenge, in: Kredit und Kapital, 27. Jahrgang, S. 319 - 347.  Google Scholar
  78. Varian, Hal R. (1982): The Nonparametric Approach to Demand Analysis, in: Econometrica, Vol. 50, S. 945 - 973. - Varian, Hal R. (1983): Non-parametric Tests of Consumer Behaviour, in: Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 50, S. 99 110.  Google Scholar
  79. Varian, Hal R. (1994): Mikroökonomie, 3. Auflage, R. Oldenbourg, München.  Google Scholar

Abstract

Divisia Money Supply Index. A Proposal on Theoretically Correct Monetary Recording?

The present contribution analyses the proposal not to measure “money supply” by unweighted aggregate sums, but by a Divisia index. The two fundamentals of this proposal are the (microeconomic) aggregation theory and the statistical index-number theory. The aggregation theory-based considerations originate in assumptions about an economic actor’s optimisation behaviour, in the course of which “money” creates benefit for being eligible as a medium of exchange. Any benefitcreating aggregate must be consistent with the maximisation behaviour. The crucial condition for being classified as money is the poor separability of the monetary components. This can be verified with the help of both parametric and nonparametric tests. The aggregation function need not be specified for the mere reason that any discretionary function can be approximated by a group of especially appropriate (first-class) index numbers. The group of such first-class index numbers includes, inter alia, the divisia index (steady over time) and its discrete approximation (Törngvist-Theil-Index). Besides the criticism voiced about the microeconomic bases (e.g. about the model of a representative benefit-maximising economic actor or about direct monetary benefit), the main problem about the divisia approach is one of empirical implementation insofar as the price of the monetary components (user costs) is concerned. In practice, it has turned out to be difficult to make the necessary modification of the user costs ascertained on the basis of the observable market interest rates so that these can hardly be expected to correctly reflect the means-of-exchange characteristic of the monetary components and will thus lead to distorted weights in the divisia index.